Investor utility depends on changes in wealth rather than levels of wealth in theory.

1. Introduction

Investment is defined as investment activity or activity, while an investor is a person or legal entity with the money to invest or invest. Investment is the placement of a fund that we have today, hoping that it will bring benefits in the future (Nguyen et al., 2020). When we invest, at least we have planned to have a better life in the future. Investments are classified into two categories: investment in financial assets and investment in real assets. The capital market has a critical role in investment because transactions occur between owners of capital and companies that issue investment products (Sarsour & Sabri, 2020). Investment products, such as stocks, can provide substantial returns but are always directly proportional to considerable risks. Investors should first know some of the information needed before investing, such as information about stock prices. This is important because when investors do not see any information about investments, especially stocks, it could be an investor’s loss. Moreover, stocks do have a significant risk, so a lot of accurate information is required before making investments. (Mittal, 2010). In a recent study, Khanam (2017) also reported the influence of demographic factors such as age, level of education, occupation, trading experience, and level of investor income. In contrast, behavioral finance researchers argue that investors tend to behave irrationally in the investment decision-making process due to the influence of several psychological factors (Kiyilar & Acar, 2013; López-Gutiérrez et al., 2015; Chen et al., 1995). Moreover, through the reflection of the prospect theory perspective on finance behavior, it has been concluded by some opinions and definitions that behavioral finance is a subsystem of psychology in the Economics field (Pompian & Wood, 2006; Kiyilar & Acar, 2013).

Another irrational consideration of investors in making investment decisions is herding which is defined as a followup to the behavior of others after comparing the beliefs and information they have on a particular investment (Hirshleifer & Hong Teoh, 2003). It is mostly caused by the prediction errors of investors to invest in a business based on the decisions of others (Scharfstein & Stein, 1990). In addition, a previous study by Nofsinger and Sias (1999) explained that herding occurs due to the movement of a group of investors in the same direction and at the same period. This means herding behavior is specifically a tendency to follow what other people are doing based on their knowledge, understanding, and experience to avoid bad judgement from the failure of the decisions made and also to ensure there is less burden of loss which has the ability of having a significant psychological impact on the investors (Deng et al., 2018).

Apart from herding, there are other cognitive factors and psychological aspects affecting investment decision making and an example is overconfidence. It is defined as a tendency for people to overestimate their knowledge, abilities, and information (Bhandari & Deaves, 2006). Moreover, a high self-confidence in an investor’s ability and knowledge usually leads to a higher belief in the ability to predict, analyze, and make accurate decisions compared to others (Shefrin, 2007). For example, the studies conducted by Gervais and Odean, (2001) and Alrabadi et al. (2011) showed that an increase in investor’s experience affects the level of overconfidence. Furthermore, increasingly overconfident investors are usually brave in making investment decisions through the use of the knowledge and information held and tend not to conform to herding. However, both herding and overconfidence factors are driven by emotional factors and they are an essential aspect of every individual with the ability to influence the decision-making process, either positively or negatively (Ackert et al., 2003).

From the financial decision-making perspective, emotional factors are classified into two aspects, loss aversion, and regret aversion. Loss aversion is one of many factors influencing investment decisions through the determination of the level of courage required by an individual to take a risk (Kahneman, 1979) and it was introduced by Thaler (1980) in a risky decision in prospect theory. It involves a situation where a person holds shares longer when experiencing loss and sell when there is a profit. This was reiterated by Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler (1990) and Haigh and List (2005) that the level of sensitivity of a person to losses is more than doubled compared to the profits obtained even though the benefits achieved also increased. Loss aversion significantly affects investment decisions especially in determining if an investor has a riskseeking or risk-averse tendencies. Moreover, in relation to herding, investors usually in a loss aversion position tend to act alone in making investment decisions.

On the contrary, regret aversion is defined as the fear of taking actions to avoid making the same mistakes while making investment decisions and it is majorly associated with the avoidance of losses. Therefore, the existence of fear influences the decision-making process in such a way that if an investor is classified as risk-averse, after facing losses, is likely to be emotionally discouraged to invest. Moreover, in relation to herding, investors suffering continuous losses are usually less confident and this makes them follow the decisions of others (Pompian & Wood, 2006). Psychological factors in investment decision making can be balanced with good and optimal financial literacy abilities (Kim, 2004; Akims & Jagongo, 2017). Financial literacy is defined as the ability and knowledge to manage income and expenditure through the use of monetary exchange and management methods (Sarigül, 2014). It is often associated with an understanding of daily activities such as insurance, credit, savings, loans, investments, and fund management to increase wealth. Moreover, financial management is essential for all professions, especially investment actors, and excellent financial literacy support has been discovered to have the ability to improve investors’ overconfidence and minimize herding.

Therefore, this study was conducted to first investigate and reconfirm the psychological role of real asset investors, especially those focusing on auctions such as land, cars, house buildings, warehouses or factories, etc. for resale, in Indonesia. Second, adopt and reinvestigate the results obtained from a study conducted by Khanam (2017) to determine the influence of several intervening variables such as loss aversion, regret aversion, financial literacy, herding, and overconfidence on investment decisions. However, Khanam (2017) and several similar studies have made use of respondents in financial asset investments while this study was focused on real asset investors.

This research was conducted to achieve several objectives and they include 1) determining if the same financial decision-making behavior in financial asset investments also apply to the investments in the real assets. Some factors are considered crucial for investments in the real assets compared to financial asset sector and these include the need for large budget to win an auction, completeness or formal legal assets, as well as the condition of the assets being auctioned, and 2) to empirically test and confirm the relationship between herding and overconfidence factors to the level of loss aversion, regret aversion, financial literacy in making real asset investment decisions.

2. Literature Review

2.1. The Finance Behavioral and Prospect Theory

Initially, individuals who make investments not only use estimates of the prospects for investment instruments, but psychological factors also determine the investment decisions. The existence of these psychological factors affect investment decisions and the results to be achieved (Xiao, 2008). Investment analysis using psychology and financial science is known as economic behavior or financial behavior. Shefrin (2007) defines behavioral finance as a study about how psychological phenomena affects financial behavior. The stock players’ behavior is where Shefrin states the practitioners’ level of action. Marilena and Alice (2012) define financial behavior as how humans behave in a financial setting. Before the emergence of the behavioral finance theory, there was a traditional theory or fundamental economics which links finance to economic theory with the assumption that all participants have the same information in the market. Moreover, most of the internal factors causing irrational actions are psychological (Sahi et al., 2013) and also serve as the basis for desires, motivations, and sources of error due to the possibilities of excessive overconfidence, wrong perception, illiteracy, and inability to control emotions, especially negative ones (Michailova & Schmidt, 2016; Meier & De Mello, 2019). Therefore, the gap between the fundamental theory and actual market conditions led to the introduction of the behavioral finance theory to address the influence of psychology on financial behavior (Shefrin, 2007; Bhandari & Deaves, 2006). However, the Prospect Theory was initiated by Kahneman (1979) as a part of behavioral finance to explain the behavior of investors.

Prospect theory was formulated to criticize the utility of approaches deemed less able to explain individual behavior in making decisions. Kahneman and Tversky (2013) stated the expected utility theory is dominated by the analysis of risk-making decisions as a normative model for rational choice and widely applied to describe economic behavior. Furthermore, Kahneman (1979) focused on the cognitive and heuristic biases causing unexpected irrational actions of investors (Kliger & Tsur, 2011). Therefore, the prospect theory is established on the principle that there is a tendency for someone to act irrationally due to the reluctance to risk gains compared to losses (Cianci, 2008). The theory is depicted by Kahneman and Tversky (2013) in a hypothetical value function to explain the role of values based on the deviation from the reference point of gain and loss. However, it has been discovered that the loss position has a more significant influence in terms of psychology than gain (Braga & Fávero, 2017). This was associated with the high sense of low self-esteem and regret observed with the loss compared to the pleasure obtained from receiving again.

2.2. Investment Decision-Making

This is an investor’s action to invest funds in several investment options, both in the financial and real assets (Hilton, 2001; Cheng, 2014). Investing in any business requires the consideration of several factors, both external and internal. External factors include the company’s financial statements, inflation, prevailing interest rates, or several supporting letters for the existence of assets (Sevdalis & Harvey, 2007; Oehler et al., 2018). Internal factors are mostly psychological and involve cognitive, affective and psychomotor levels (Statman, 2017). The cognitive aspect is related to intellectual ability and thinking both in terms of knowledge, understanding, application, analysis, evaluation, and others while affective includes ethical behavior, feelings, attitudes, emotions, and others. The emergence of psychological biases in behavioral finance tends to shift rational to irrational actions while making investment decisions (Peters, 2003). According to Mittal (2010), a biased and sometimes irrational behavior of an investor is greatly influenced by emotions and mood during the investment decision-making process. This is in accordance with the submission of Kahneman (1979), and Kahneman and Tversky (2013) that when humans are in a state of uncertainty, there is a shift from fundamental economic theory in making investment decisions. It was also reinforced by the opinion of Brunsson (2014) that uncertainty shows the decision-makers’ lack of confidence in the information available and risks due to the difficulty experienced in decision making. This uncertainty was also found to be caused by the possibility of cognitive structure, unclear judgment, and change of estimation (Brunsson, 2014). Furthermore, internal factors also dominate in influencing the courage exhibited by an investor, either as a risk-seeking or risk averter, in making investment decisions (Kliger & Tsur, 2011; Fong, 2013; He & Choi, 2020; Nguyen, 2020).

2.3. Herding Behavior

Herding occurs due to the movement of a group of investors in the same direction and at the same period (Nofsinger & Sias, 1999). It is a behavior involving the tendency to mimic the actions of others rather than follow the information and knowledge obtained personally (Hirshleifer & Teoh, 2003; Rompotis, 2018). According to Land and Rose (2011), it is defined as an individual’s propensity to follow others in making the same investment due to the lack of public information. This was also confirmed by Jurkatis, Kremer, and Nautz, (2012) that the concept emerged due to the lack of transparency in the market place leading to uncertain public information sources and unclear corporate signals. Baddeley et al. (2012), Andersson et al. (2014) and Alda and Ferruz(2016) also reported the occurrence of herding due to the restriction of public data and information to certain groups in decision making. However, (Venezia et al., 2011) argued there are rational herding actions as observed from some pieces of literature and they include information-based, reputationbased, and compensation-based (Venezia et al., 2011).

Information-based herding involves using the data gathered from observing other investors that have earlier invested in stock to correct error bias (Venezia et al., 2011; Banerjee, 1992; Bikhchandani et al., 1992). Reputationbased herding involves a situation where two managers and employer investments are not sure of the skills possessed by the two managers (Venezia et al., 2011; Froot et al., 1992). Compensation-based herding involves the initial compensation of an investment manager associated with several market benchmarks and the discovery of activities to be mimicked or copied by other investors (Venezia et al., 2011; Maug & Naik, 1996). The major element of rational herding is the reception of the same signal by investors towards making the same decision in order to maximize profits while irrational herding involves decisions made in a panic and emotional condition due to other investors’ shares or asset transactions and which causes instability if any unexpected error occurs in both the financial and asset markets. For the purpose of this research, the scope was limited to herding behavior in making investment decisions on real assets (Lee & Lee, 2015).

2.4. Overconfidence

Overconfidence is defined to be an excessive feeling of confidence with the ability to make investors have the courage to see risk as being insignificant when making decisions (Deaves et al., 2019; Morales-Camargo et al., 2015). Conversely, those with less confidence tend towards being cautious in making risky investment decisions because the risk is considered a big problem (Stotz & von Nitzsch, 2005). Moreover, overconfidence makes investors overestimate their knowledge and underrate predictions due to the fact they believe more in their abilities than they should (Nofsinger, 2017). In another study, the concept is defined as the tendency of an individual to overvalue its knowledge, abilities, and information (Bhandari & Deaves, 2006). This is associated with several factors such as gender, age, experience, past performance, advice, and management qualification. It has also been discovered that uncertainties can lead to overconfidence through the process of making overestimated decisions (Fischhoff, 2003; Kartini & Setiawan, 2017; Stotz & von Nitzsch, 2005). Shefrin (2007) reported overconfidence bias is divided into two – based on ability and knowledge. Furthermore, there is ability to predict, analyze, and make accurate decisions when an individual has a high level of confidence compared to others, however, it has also been reported that overrated selfconfidence is only an illusion of experience and skill due to limited or lack of expertise in interpreting information (Baker & Nofsinger, 2002; Lovric et al., 2010). This, therefore, means it is possible for investors to become overconfident through advice obtained from those with more experience in the field, and the level of experience determines the rate at which an individual is overconfident (Gervais & Odean, 2001; Alrabadi et al., 2011).

2.5. Emotional Bias

Emotions are an essential aspect of an individual with an influence on the outcome of a decision (Ackert et al., 2003). According to Hirshleifer (2001), emotions play an important role in ambiguous conditions, especially when individuals are afraid to take risks (Riff & Yagil, 2016). This shows the significance of psychology - both affective which involves emotions and cognitive which involve the intellect, knowledge, and sensitivity of an individual in the process of making any business decision. This was affirmed by the Decision Affect Theory that emotions from some selected actions have effects on decisions (Mellers et al., 1997; Mellers et al., 1999; Guzak, 2015). This is mostly observed in how an individual learns, remembers, thinks, takes risks, receives, or understands very complex social information associated with decision-making (Bower, 1981; Bless et al., 1996). There are several factors of emotions affecting financial decisions and they include loss aversion, regret aversion, or the status quo. However, this study was limited to only two of these, and they are loss and regret aversions.

2.6. Loss Aversion

Loss aversion is a process of holding more shares of stock in the event of a loss to sell when there is profit (Kahneman, 1979). It is also defined as the tendency of an individual to be more sensitive when there is loss compared to when there is a gain (Thaler et al., 1997). People with loss aversion are more cautious in making investments during the period when there is no profit in comparison with the times there is enough gain (Haigh & List, 2005). It also involves holding the stock when the market experiences losses with the expectation the price is going to increase in the future. These definitions and explanations show individuals possessing loss aversion are less daring and tend to have herding behavior while making investment decisions and vice versa (Dräger et al., 2014). Based on the explanations, the following hypotheses were formulated:

H1: Loss aversion affects investment decision

H2: Loss aversion through herding as an intervening variable influences investment decision

2.7. Regret Aversion

This is defined as the fear of taking actions to avoid making the same mistakes while making investment decisions (Pompian & Wood, 2006; Chorus, 2014; Corzo et al., 2014). This concept emerged due to the desire of investors to avoid the expected regrets which comes from making wrong investment decisions. It also creates concerns for both individual and group investors over price fluctuations which may cause losses in real estate and current financial assets in the market. Moreover, the main idea behind this concept involves holding back poorly performing stocks and selling the shares when the market shows a profit. According to Pompian and Wood (2006), regret aversion has the ability to make investors become too conservative and under-risk against the market due to the continuous losses being experienced and this may consequently lead to herding. This phenomenon serves as the foundation for the regret theory developed by Loomes and Sugden (1982) and Bell (1982) which is considered an irrational theory of choice in uncertainty conditions. However, for the purpose of this study, the regret aversion was explained based on prospect theory.

H3: Regret aversion influences investment decisions.

H4: Regret aversion through herding as an intervening variable influences investment- decisions.

2.8. Financial Literacy

Financial science is dynamic and firmly attached to everyday practices, therefore, absolute financial knowledge is optimally required, especially when an individual is offered several commercial products. Making the right decision requires adequate knowledge, information, and understanding of finances and other things attached to it. Cole and Fernando (2008) defined financial literacy as the ability to read, analyze, manage, and write the finances affecting the life of a person. According to Abreu and Mendes (2010), only a few know the impact of this concept on investment diversification and its ability to explain problems with investor behavior. A study conducted (e.g., Aryeetey, 2004; Kim, 2004; Akims & Jagongo, 2017; Ahunov & van Hove, 2019; Gil, 2015) found the effect of financial literacy on financial decision-making. These, however, led to the formulation of the following hypotheses:

H5: Financial literacy affects investment decisions.

H6: Financial literacy through herding as an intervening variable influences investment- decisions.

H7: Financial literacy through overconfidence as an intervening variable influences investment-decisions.

H8: Financial literacy through overconfidence and herding as an intervening variable influences investment-decisions

Table 1: Measurement of Variable.

3. Research Methods and Materials

The samples used include 105 real estate auction investors at the State Assets and Auction Service Office (KPKNL) South Sulawesi, Indonesia that has participated in a real asset auction 1-10 times and selected using purposive sampling. Data was collected using a questionnaire consisting of 23 questions as shown in Table 2 and analyzed using quantitative analysis. Likert scale ranging from 1 for strongly disagree to 5 for strongly agree was used. The three independent variables used include Loss Aversion (X1) consisting of three constructs (X1.1 - X1.3), Regret aversion (X2) consisting of two constructs (X2.1 - X2.2), and Financial literacy (X3) consisting of five constructs (X3.1 - X3.5).

Table 2: Outer Model and Inner Mode

Furthermore, two intervening variables were used including Overconfidence (X4) which is composed of two construct items (X4.1 - X4.2) and Herding (X5) consisting of five constructs (X5.1 - X5.5). The dependent variable was the Investment Decision (Y) with six constructs (Y1 - Y6). In addition, the model developed included the moderation and intervening effects of financial literacy and overconfidence variables as shown in Figure 1. The research data was tested for reliability and validity (Hair et al., 2017), (Chin, 1998), through the use of Cronbach alpha, composite reliability, F-test, R-square, with AVE > 0.60 and outer-loading > 0.50 through the application of non-parametric statistical applications Smart-PLS and reviewed using the Consistent PLS-Algorithm section with the criteria being the weighting scheme path and maximum literation of 300. Moreover, the hypotheses were tested to determine the magnitude of the coefficient of influence and relationship in the consistentbootstrapping sub-section with 105 sub-sample and confidence interval method using the Bias-Corrected and accelerated (BCa) Bootstrap two-tailed at a sig. level of 0.05.

Figure 1: Model Analysis of Smart-PLS

4. Results and Discussion

4.1. Results

The inner model was used to measure the interior or structural model connecting the latent variables through the use of R-Squared or R2 . Moreover, the results obtained from the outer and inner statistical tests are presented in Table 2 and supported by the model fit in Fig 1.

Table 2 shows all the latent variables have values of Cronbach’s alpha greater than 0.6 and this means they are all reliable without any reflective indicators. This was also supported by the results from composite reliability which were also greater than 0.7 while the validity test showed a greater convergent. Besides, the model also showed the value of the outer model by measuring the efficacy through the use of both convergent and discriminant validity. The convergent validity showed each latent variable has AVE value greater than 0.5 and this means they have the ability to explain more than half the variants for all indicators on the average. This was also supported by discriminant validity where the cross-loading of each latent variable showed a value > 0.7 to indicate they are not highly correlated. This, therefore, means the outer model of this study is reliable and valid.

The inner model measured with R Square includes endogenous latent variables including herding, investment, and overconfidence. Herding has a R2 value of 0.893 as a model in the current category, Investment has 0.784 in the active group, while Overconfidence has 0.601 and was placed in the moderate category

The path coefficient was used to determine the latent variable predictor of the structural level with the criteria being that if f2 is 0.02 it is weak, 0.15 is enough, while 0.35 is strong. The results in Table 3 show the robust predictor was observed with regret aversion to herding and financial literacy to overconfidence, sufficiency was found with loss aversion to herding path while the other lines showed weak predictors. After the conduct of the outer and inner model as well as the path coefficient, the hypotheses were tested using PLS-SEM at a significance level of 10% and the results are presented in Table 3.

Table 3: Path coefficient (F2)

Table 4 shows the loss aversion and investment decision have a significant positive effect as observed with the P-value of 0.033 which is below the 10% significance level used in this study. This means more loss aversion would lead to less courage in making investment decisions. The same was found with the use of herding as the intervening variable with the result showing a negative effect as observed from a P-Value of 0.033 and a sample mean of -0.185. Moreover, there was no adverse significant effect of financial literacy on Herding with the P-value of 0.109 which is higher than the 10% significance level but financial literacy had an adverse effect on investment decisions. The same was also found with the use of herding as an intervening variable. On the contrary, through the intervention of overconfidence and herding, financial literacy was found in a positive direction and with no effect on investment decisions. Furthermore, there was no significant relationship between other variables including overconfidence on investment decisions, financial literacy on overconfidence, financial literacy on herding through overconfidence, and overconfidence on investment decisions through the use of herding as the intervening variable.

Table 4: Hypothesis Test Results

4.2. Discussions

The findings showed an individual with increasing loss aversion tends to be more afraid to make investment decisions, and is mostly risk-averse. This is in line with the description of Kahneman and Tversky (1979) and Kahneman (1979a) that a person in a losing position would hold the stock longer up to when there is enough profit in the business. Moreover, even though the respondents of this research were real asset investors with experience in auctioning of assets such as houses, cars, factories, warehouses, and others requiring considerable funds, the results showed if assets auctioned are offered at lower prices, investors would make a quick purchase and vice versa. Furthermore, assets obtained through auction would also be resold as fast as possible when the market price rises and considered to be beneficial. Conversely, if the price of the asset owned decreases or when the increase does not correspond with the effort, the asset would be retained and not released for sale. Therefore, the simple logic is to hold assets owned when prices go down and sell when it rises in order to earn significant profits. But when getting a benefit is considered something normal that should be obtained. Furthermore, this study showed real assets investors have a cautious tendency in making investment decisions due to the consideration of several things such as the physical condition and completeness of the documents guaranteeing the security of the assets to avoid having greater loss and regret.

Loss aversion was found to have a negative influence on decision making through the use of herding variables as the mediator to affirm the first hypothesis. However, the path analysis showed a positive impact between loss aversion and herding and this means investors with high loss aversion tend to exhibit herding behavior. Moreover, the reason some real estate investors believe more in the information, advice, knowledge, and actions obtained from others in deciding on an investment is to ensure the blame from the loss is shared and to reduce the feeling of regret. However, the mean sample showed investors with high loss aversion and tendency to herd are not too dominating because they are cautious about the information, advice, and actions not obtained from others. This shows despite the fact they tend to decide based on others’ direction, they tend to be more careful during the process. Furthermore, investors with loss aversion sometimes do not herd due to some important factors attached to investment such as the significant funds required, ownership validity, bureaucracy, and whether or not the assets can be resold. After the auction has been won, investors become highly afraid and cautious due to the loss aversion. Besides, the courage level is not only influenced by external factors but also by internal ones especially from the affective side like emotions. This is in agreement with the findings of Ackert et al. (2003) that emotions play an essential part, either negative or positive, in decision-making

On the contrary, hypothetically, if an investor has a low loss aversion there is a tendency to make investment decisions primarily based on the information and advice obtained from others. This means the less perception of loss aversion leads to a greater tendency to exhibit herding behavior as well as a high level of courage in making investment decisions. Moreover, an investor with a low level of loss aversion usually has a high sense of regret after a loss and, therefore, continuously prefers herding. The respondents showed a position of loss aversion by being extra careful in a situation of loss and this is in agreement with the findings of Haigh & List, (2005) that real asset auction investors deliberately assume tangible assets with a high level of market prices are to be immediately resold while those deemed unprofitable should be retained until the price rises. These actions both during the auction and resell basically follows the prospect theory of Kahneman (1979). It is important to note that the findings of this study regarding the relationship between loss aversion and herding are not precisely in line with previous studies like Haigh and List (2005). However, the overall effect of herding, as intervening variables, strengthens the negative influence between loss aversion and investment decisions as hypothesized. Aversion retreat is defined as the actions caused by the influence of an individual’s emotions. In line with the studies of Ackert et al. (2003) and Pompian (2006.) showing the influence of emotions on individual decisions, positive or negative, the regret aversion was due to the feelings of fear to take actions in order to avoid the same mistakes and this was found to be influenced by previous good or bad experiences, specifically for auctioned goods. These could be through the excessive fear of huge losses, both financially and nonfinancially as well as other things to be considered such as the completeness of the required documents, bureaucracy in the region, and the nature of the assets won.

The negative impact of financial literacy on investment decisions is contrary to the findings(Cole & Fernando, 2008; Vitt, 2005; Shefrin, 2007) where a higher level of financial literacy led to the ability to process more information and make personal decisions. It also contradicts other previous studies due to the fact real asset investors used in this study were faced with valuable information which required careful consideration before an investment decision was made. Moreover, the finding showing financial literacy does not influence overconfidence is supported by Gervais and Odean (2001) and Alrabadi et al. (2011).

5. Conclusion

There is a slight difference in the decision-making process for real asset and financial asset investors. This is observed in the fact that financial asset investors have a large number of shares offered and the number purchased depends on the funds held while real asset investors have limited assets which are contested by many investors and only won with significant funds. Moreover, there the variation in the bureaucracy and information is such that investments in financial asset sector requires less complicated decisions compared to real asset where there are a lot of administrative problems to be considered based on the asset auctioned as well as other things such as the validity of asset ownership, strategic location, cost of repairs, and uncertain time of resale. Even though excellent financial literacy has the ability to increase the level of overconfidence, it does not influence decision-making instantly due to several other factors to be considered.

How does behavior and psychology play a role in investment decisions?

Behavioral finance is the study of the effects of psychology on investors and financial markets. It focuses on explaining why investors often appear to lack self-control, act against their own best interest, and make decisions based on personal biases instead of facts.

What are the two major concepts of behavioral finance?

Behavioral finance is the study of understanding people's irrational financial decisions. The two main building blocks are cognitive psychology and the limits to arbitrage.

Why do investors make irrational or inefficient decisions?

Overconfidence Bias Overconfidence is an emotional bias. Overconfident investors believe they have more control over their investments than they truly do. Since investing involves complex forecasts of the future, overconfident investors may overestimate their abilities to identify successful investments.

What are some of the more important disagreements between the efficient market hypothesis and the findings of behavioral finance?

When efficient market hypothesis is considered, the assumption is that the price of stock market will reach equilibrium since prices are informationally efficient. However, behavioral finance claim that investors tend to have some psychological and emotional biases which lead to irrationality.